Author Archives Paul McConnell

Aligning Tax Policy with Sound Executive Compensation Practices

Posted by Paul McConnell on May 26, 2009  /   Posted in Compensation Committees

If we want executives to act and be rewarded like investors, we should tax them like investors.

As the chorus of public outrage over executive compensation rises to a new crescendo, it is understandable why the populist approach to “solve” executive pay is through regulatory pay limits. However, executive compensation experts and investor representatives alike agree that rather than limiting pay, the best thinking on the subject is focused on creating plans where executive wealth is tied to that of long-term investors – where they are unable to profit (or limit losses) from short-term changes in company performance or company stock price. There is much agreement that this linkage is best accomplished through executive equity arrangements with provisions such as “hold-till-retirement” requirements. However, in implementing these provisions boards of directors are now finding that federal tax policy is not aligned with what is arguably in the best interest of the public, not to mention shareholders.

We believe that minor changes to the tax code could facilitate these ownership provisions, thus providing greater alignment of executive pay with public interests. Further, these changes will also increase federal revenues by increasing the effective tax on executive pay without the adverse economic effect of broad rate increases. Simply put, we recommend that the tax code cease treating certain long-term executive equity incentives as annual “compensation”, and instead treat it like an investment.

Current Tax Law Rewards an Early Exit

The table below shows the current taxation of various popular executive equity compensation vehicles:

Vehicle Form of Income Timing
Restricted Stock or Performance Shares Full value is Compensation Vesting
Nonqualified Stock Option (NQSO) Gain is Compensation Exercise
Incentive Stock Option (ISO) Gain is Capital Gains Sale of shares

Any compensation value from an executive equity grant is also deductible to the employer (subject to the limits and performance rules of section 162(m)) and is subject to Medicare taxes (1.45% rate) from both the executive and the employer.

The net effect of this approach is that today’s executives have a powerful incentive to exercise stock options during favorable market cycles, then liquidate their positions to provide cash flow to execute the exercise, including withholding taxes. Since there is no further tax liability and typically little obligation beyond perhaps modest stock holding requirements, a rational executive/investor would clearly sell their ownership position and interests to diversify their overall portfolio. The existing tax treatment does not encourage long-term executive ownership nor penalize sale of stock during the executive’s career.

Alternative Tax Approach Creates Value from Holding to Retirement

An alternative approach is to treat executive equity awards as a sale of company stock on the date of grant, similar to any other investor purchasing shares for cash. Where there is a discount element (e.g., restricted stock or performance shares), the discount at grant would be treated as compensation to the executive and deductible to the company (subject to 162(m)). However, the tax on this compensation would not be due until it was both vested and sold. Thus a company could create a very favorable tax situation for its executives (and an incentive benefiting investors and the public alike) by requiring that they hold the stock until after they leave the company. Like other investors, any post-grant gain (or loss) would be taxed as a capital gain at the time of sale. Similarly, any dividends paid would be taxed at the 15% rate (under current law).

Vehicle Form of Income Timing
Restricted Stock or Performance Shares Value at grant is Compensation, any post-grant change is Capital Gain (Loss) Sale of Shares
Stock Options [1] Gain is Capital Gains Sale of shares

These proposed tax rules create a strong incentive for executives and Boards to design equity plans utilizing hold–till-retirement provisions. For example, without a hold-till-retirement provision a performance share grant would trigger immediate taxation for the full value at vesting. The executive would typically then sell shares to satisfy the withholding tax. With the benefit of a hold-till-retirement provision, the executive would not be liable for any tax until the shares were sold – at some point after retirement. This will result in more net shares remaining in the hands of executives, presumably providing a more significant incentive for delivering long-term results for investors and the public at large.

Curiously, although the executive would receive favorable tax treatment, the tax revenue gains to the government would be significant. Currently, the executive’s ordinary income tax and the corporate deduction largely offset each other. As a result, the executive’s basis in the stock is stepped up to the price at the date of vesting (for full value shares) or exercise (in the case of an option). Thus the net tax received by the federal government is limited to the capital gains tax calculated on any stock appreciation subsequent to vesting/exercise – and there is little incentive for executives to hold shares after vesting/exercise.

Under the proposed approach, the executive’s capital gains would be measured from the grant date price – as is the case with an investor purchase – with no offsetting tax deduction by the corporation. While this results in a lower tax rate for the executive, the effective taxation is increased by eliminating the employer’s tax deduction. Furthermore, the combination of hold-till-retirement covenants and supporting tax policy better aligns the executive performance incentive with the interests of investors and the public over time, rather than allowing an executive group to be rewarded for short term results. With a broad definition of equity incentive plans (i.e., including non-public company equity and equity-like vehicles), this approach can successfully apply regardless of company size or ownership structure (e.g., small businesses, joint ventures, subsidiaries, private equity and start-ups).

We believe this is an easily achievable first step toward aligning federal tax policy with public policy interests regarding executive compensation and corporation accountability. If we want executives to act and be rewarded like investors, we should tax them like investors.

– Paul McConnell

Paul McConnell works with a number of Board Advisory clients within the banking and related financial services arena on executive pay alignment, performance measurement, and executive performance issues. You can view Mr. McConnell’s bio here. If you have any question or comments on this article, or want to speak with Paul about any executive rewards, performance, or succession issue, he can be reached at pmcconnell@board-advisory.com, or at (407)876-7249.

[1] The tax code changes proposed in this article could be achieved by simply modifying existing ISO provisions in IRC sections 421 through 424, to reflect contemporary executive pay programs and hold-till-retirement obligations.

Download this article in the PDF format.

Will Executive Incentives Keep the “Bailout” from Working?

Posted by Paul McConnell on January 28, 2009  /   Posted in Compensation Committees

The infusion of hundreds of billions of dollars of taxpayer funds into the domestic financial system has created a fundamental change in the ownership structure of most banks.  By establishing the U.S. government as the largest single shareholder in many of the TARP-participating banks, there is a divergence in shareholder objectives.   The government as an investor has provided cheap, patient capital in the form of preferred stock that only requires a 5% annual dividend and no price appreciation.  The Government has invested in these banks with the intention that these investments would stabilize the financial industry and get credit flowing again to the broader economy.  It wants financial recovery, job creation and economic growth.  However, historic financial industry practices and the incentive compensation arrangements offered to executives at these institutions may be working directly against the government’s public objectives.

The traditional investor objectives of maximizing economic value through growth in earnings and increased rate of return on capital employed, and the incentives that reward these results, are the heart of the conflict.  When faced with difficult economic times such as we are currently seeing, the natural reaction (as motivated by these incentive plans) is to avoid the loss of capital, cut off lenders that don’t meet high credit standards and generally batten down the hatches.  It is no surprise that bankers are acting consistent with their objectives and their financial interests.

Alternative Approach

If the “bailout” is to succeed, we need to find some way to reconcile these divergent interests.  It wouldn’t make sense to change the incentives for the bank as a whole; The Government’s investment is big, but it is only 10-20% of the total equity in these banks.  The other shareholder’s interests must be respected as well.  But to clarify objectives and maintain accountability for results within the institutions, one possibility is to build a new organization within the banks that is focused on the needs of this new, unique shareholder.  This “Rescue Bank” can be a separate legal corporation or an autonomous division, but it needs special staffing, leadership, and incentives that are attuned to the unique goals of its shareholder.  It is likely that the strongest economic impact will come from the small to medium sized businesses that have historically been the engine of job creation.  A large number of these are suffering from overextension, a shortage of capital and customers that cannot buy their products due to lack of financing.  These accounts could be transferred to the Rescue Bank, along with appropriate loss reserves that will create a level playing field.  Then the Rescue Bank could help these companies by utilizing flexible credit standards, refinancing, pools of investment capital and inexpensive financing facilities for their customers.

The Rescue Bank would need to be staffed by seasoned commercial bankers that have been through economic downturns and who are experienced in lending to troubled companies and by investment bankers that can help restructure balance sheets and provide creative secured lending.  The management group would comprise leaders that see beyond the bank’s balance sheet to its obligation of providing access to capital and general financial liquidity to the public.

Aligned Incentives: Executive & Employee Pay Plans

We know from experience that employee and management incentives do motivate the behavior that is asked for.  But if executive and employee pay plans are built around net income and financial returns, we will not get the kind of actions that this situation or this shareholder requires.  Instead, a very significant portion of the employees’ annual compensation should be tied to such metrics as: client revenue growth; job creation or saves; GDP growth within the market area; business startups; and public approval.

We don’t want these bankers to totally ignore the concept of profits, after all the Government money does need to be repaid.  Long-term incentives could be designed to balance the annual goals by investing a slice of the parent’s capital along with the government’s money (e.g., $1 for every $5 of TARP dollars).  This “common stock” would be credited with any Recovery Bank financial returns in excess of the 5% required on the preferred stock.  Grants of book value phantom shares (with conversion rights to the parent common stock) that vest when the TARP money is repaid would provide a powerful leverage to get this troubled economy up and running again.  If the Rescue Bank’s annual return on total equity only reaches 7%, these awards would grow by 17% that year – plus any kick from the recovery the parent’s stock price.

Incentives do work.  If we create the right ones for this situation, we as a country can more quickly work our way out of this difficult financial situation.

– Paul McConnell

Download this article in the PDF format.
© 2009 Board Advisory.
^ Back to Top